Promoting SME R&D and Innovation

By Hiroyuki Okamuro, Junichi Nishimura, Massimo Colombo, and Erik Stam

Abstract

SMEs are subject to constraints in internal resources including capital, human resources and knowledge due to small size. Moreover, access to external resources is limited as well due to market failures. Thus, SMEs have disadvantages in R&D and innovation compared to larger firms. In order to overcome these gaps with large firms, various public policies have been implemented including financial, networking, and IPR support programs. We discuss the effectiveness of these policies based on empirical evidence and propose a better policy framework for SME’s R&D and innovation with special attention to networking and IPR support programs.

Challenge

Constraints of SMEs for R&D and innovation

Innovation is a major engine of economic growth. Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), which account for most of the enterprises, are expected to significantly contribute to innovation. However, it is known that SMEs’ contribution to research and development (R&D) activities is limited (Terziovski 2010). According to the 4th National Innovation Survey in Japan, only 11% of SMEs (<250 employees) achieved product innovation during 2012-2014 compared to 27% for large firms (NISTEP 2016). Some reasons may be pointed out for the relatively low level of R&D and innovation by SMEs worldwide1. Many SMEs may not be interested in R&D and innovation, but we can observe severe SME resource constraints for conducting R&D and innovation activities2.

1. Constraints of internal business resources

Due to their small size, SMEs face severe constraints in internal resources, such as capital (funding), human resources, and advanced knowledge. In addition to liquidity constraints, SMEs often lack sufficient knowledge and human resources to absorb external knowledge, which is essential for R&D and innovation. As opposed to larger firms, SMEs lack complementary assets for innovation, including intellectual property protection (Cockburn and Henderson 2001; Hall and Ziedonis 2001; Ceccagnoli et al. 2010).

2. Constraints in accessibility to external resources

Therefore, SMEs should rely on external business resources to conduct R&D activities. They must seek external funding and collaborate with other organizations to obtain advanced knowledge. Capital constraints are severe for SME R&D activities because of high uncertainty and information asymmetry

(Hall and Lerner 2010; Hottenrott and Peters 2012; Mancusi and Vezzulli 2014). Recent studies suggest the importance of open innovation via inter-organizational alliances (O’Sulllivan et al. 2013; Warwick and Nolan 2014), which also may be difficult for SMEs due to information asymmetry and high search and transaction costs<sup3.

3. Difficulties in protecting and utilizing intellectual property rights (IPR)

Even for innovative SMEs, it is often difficult to capture the benefits of innovation because it is difficult to build a patent portfolio, and no complementary assets (including IPR management) are available to protect their competitive advantage. Lanjouw and Schankerman (2004) show that small firms are more subject to patent litigation. Lack of complementary assets reduces marginal revenues that SMEs would obtain from R&D investment and lowers their incentive to invest in R&D. Also, lack of absorptive capacity and high search costs prevent SMEs from utilizing external IPR to their own innovative and competitive advantage.

Proposal

Who should be the targets of public support for R&D and innovation?

Social returns on R&D investments are usually higher than privates return to inventors due to the positive externality of R&D (Hall et al. 2010). Hence, policy intervention to close the gaps between actual and desired R&D levels may be warranted.

Most SMEs may suffer from internal and external resource constraints, but supporting all SMEs regardless of R&D orientation and innovation potential is inefficient and cannot be justified. On the other hand, governments tend to pick winners for their policy targets to secure positive outcomes for their support policies. However, this strategy is inefficient because these targets would conduct R&D with their own resources and achieve innovation without public support. Therefore, public policy should consider backing challengers rather than backing losers or picking up winners (Stam 2018), regardless of different economic developments and social contexts of each country. In any country and society we may find challengers for innovation who cannot secure access to resources due to market incompleteness.

What are the most binding constraints for SMEs? What policy interventions are possible to remedy these constraints?

For R&D and innovation, firms need capital, human resources, and knowledge. Traditionally, the lack of internal and external capital (funding) has been regarded as the most binding constraint to an SME’s R&D and innovation. Therefore, public policy discussion has concentrated on direct financial support through public subsidies and tax credits. It has been argued that direct financial support is important for innovative young firms and start-ups due to severe information asymmetry. Compared to these supply-side measures, demand-side measures (public procurement of innovative goods) are recognized as efficient programs.

But access to advanced knowledge may be a binding constraint for innovative SMEs. Recent studies suggest that ‘soft’ or indirect support (including matching and networking with universities and other organizations) may be more effective than ‘hard’ or direct financial support (Nishimura and Okamuro 2011). For innovative SMEs, utilizing external knowledge and protecting their own innovations via an intellectual property right (IPR) system is an important strategy. The availability of human resources is another essential constraint for SME innovation, but this Policy Brief will focus solely on access to external human resources who have advanced knowledge via collaboration with universities and other research institutes.

Various policy measures are available to promote R&D and innovation by SMEs: R&D subsidy and tax credits (deduction), networking and matching support for R&D collaboration, public innovation procurement, and a more SME-friendly IPR system. We should also consider a better balance and combination of public and private R&D investment. In the following sections, we will elaborate on each proposal in more detail.

Improving public support schemes for SMEs’ R&D activities

To resolve insufficient SME R&D investment and its outcomes, governments have been working on improving access to R&D resources for SMEs (OECD 2015). Traditional financial support policies include public subsidies and tax credits (deductions). The former may incur moral hazards and crowding out, which would lower the policy effects. Previous studies suggest that public subsidies positively affect SME’s R&D investments and their outputs, such as patents (Almus and Czarnitzki 2003; Hyytinen and Toivanen 2005; Koga 2005). Tax credits, which account for nearly half of public R&D support in OECD countries in 2015, significantly increased its share since 2006 (OECD 2017: pp. 156-157). Tax incentives may theoretically be better schemes than subsidies because they will not incur moral hazards or crowding out, whereas previous studies show mixed results or negative effects, specifically in the case of the patent box program in Europe (see Appendix).

These support schemes should be made more effective for SMEs (Keizer et al. 2002) based on empirical evidence and by appropriately considering the incentive mechanism. In addition to this traditional support, demand-side support and ‘soft’ or indirect support for R&D has recently been attracting attention.

  1. It is essential for public R&D support policies to rebuild incentive schemes based on empirical evidence (Okamuro and Nishimura 2018). Public support programs should be designed to enhance incentives to participating SMEs while discouraging moral hazards and free-riding (Nishimura and Okamuro 2018). It is also important to design an intensive monitoring scheme for public R&D support to avoid agency problems (Lerner 2002).
  2. “Soft” or indirect R&D support (including business/academic/financial matching, networking, consulting and mentoring) may be more effective for innovation than “hard” or direct support (Huggins and Johnston 2009; Ortega-Argilés et al. 2009; Martin et al. 2011; Nishimura and Okamuro 2011; Suzuki 2017). Intermediaries that match scientific seeds and market innovation needs are particularly important (Mindura 2013; Nagaoka et al. 2014; Banal-Estañol et al. 2017).
  3. In addition to traditional supply-side support measures (such as public subsidies), more attention should be paid to demand-side support measures (public procurement of innovative products). Recent studies suggest the effectiveness of such demand-side policies (Georghiou et al. 2014; Edler and Yeow 2016). Guerzoni and Raiteri (2015) indicate that demand-side policies may be more effective than supply-side policies when controlling for interaction with other policies. This policy measure provides similar benefits as selective subsidies (e.g. signaling benefits) without the associated costs for SMEs arising from the (generally) ineffective management of selective support schemes by governmental authorities.

It is noteworthy from the viewpoint of efficient evidence-based policy making (EBPM) that every support program mentioned above for SME’s R&D and innovation should be subject to a constant third-party monitoring and evaluation. It is true that it may take time for public R&D and innovation policies to be effective. These policies may have various unforeseen indirect effects. It is important to insert third-party monitoring and evaluation of support policies into relevant laws and ordinances.

Promoting public-private partnership for R&D investment in SMEs

The efficiency of public R&D support is limited due to budget constraints and potential “government failures.” The private sector (including banks and venture capital) can play an important role as a promoter of SME R&D and innovation. Banks increasingly recognize SME lending as a core strategic business (De la Torre et al. 2010). Venture capital investment in innovative SMEs has been attracting attention. But as argued above, information asymmetry is severe for R&D funding from banks and investors under uncertainty. To overcome the problems of both market and government failures, we must promote a better public-private R&D support partnership for SMEs as follows.

  1. Develop human resources for public and private agencies who can evaluate the growth and innovation potential of SMEs (Meuleman et al. 2012; Okamuro and Nishimura 2015; Nishimura et al. 2018).
  2. Build networks of investors, banks and SMEs to provide open access to investment opportunities (Nishimura and Okamuro 2011).
  3. Encouraging combinations of public and private investments to increase SME opportunities, such as matching the funds of public and private sectors (Kim et al. 2015) and public venture capital (Bertoni et al. 2015; Colombo et al. 2016).

More efficient searching for potential R&D partners

For innovative SMEs with resource constraints, R&D partnerships with other firms, universities, and public research institutes is important because they can share the costs and risks of R&D activities with their partners (Okamuro 2007) and obtain valuable resources (such as advanced knowledge) (Nishimura and Okamuro 2011). Larger firms are more likely to engage in R&D partnerships with other firms and organizations (NISTEP 2016: p. 94 and 99; OECD 2017: pp. 134-135). It may be that SMEs have difficulties searching for appropriate partners for joint R&D due to lack of information about professional researchers (NISTEP 2016: p.105). Therefore, public policy should lower SME search costs for R&D partners–

  1. by constructing comprehensive databases to link SMEs with other firms, universities, and public research institutes,
  2. by encouraging information disclosures of the market needs and scientific seeds of R&D activities and utilizing networking intermediaries (Mindruta 2013; Nagaoka et al. 2014; Banal-Estañol et al. 2017), and
  3. by directly supporting partner searches via matching events (Nishimura and Okamuro 2011).

The government should be more proactive in encouraging partnerships between SMEs and research organizations. However, it is noteworthy that sufficient absorptive capacity of SMEs is essential to efficient R&D collaboration.

Efficient protection and utilization of IPR

In addition to improving SMEs’ access to external resources, the importance of an intellectual property system for patents, trademarks and copyrights must also be emphasized (Olander et al. 2009). It is known that the intellectual property system has two contrasting purposes: protecting inventions (to provide innovation incentives to inventors) and the diffusion of new knowledge (to avoid duplicates and encourage further inventions). Therefore, the intellectual property system should be useful to SMEs both to protect their own innovations and to obtain advanced external knowledge. IPR helps SMEs enhance business performance (Helmers and Rogers 2011; Farre-Mensa et al. 2016; Nishimura et al. 2018). However, the enforcement and operation of the intellectual property system is insufficient in some countries, especially to the disadvantage of SMEs (Lanjouw and Schankerman 2004).

To promote protection and utilization of intellectual property by SMEs, it is important to improve their intellectual property literacy (Rodwell et al. 2007; Hughes and Mina 2010) and design more “SME-friendly” intellectual property systems (Harhoff et al. 2009; Rassenfosse and Jaffe 2017) by lowering thresholds for patenting. Special support for SMEs protecting their own innovations against IPR litigation, such as by providing professional, legal support, is desirable. Also, acquiring and utilizing IPR is quite costly for most SMEs (Rodwell et al. 2007). Therefore, they should have better and easier access to intellectual property databases, including trademarks and copyrights.

For the appendix, please refer to the full text policy brief here.
_____

1 Trends similar to Japan can be observed in European countries, according to the results of the Community Innovation Survey in 2014 (Eurostat).
2 According to the results of the 4th National Innovation Survey in 2014 (NISTEP 2016: p. 101), SMEs cite lack of internal funds (37%), difficulty of obtaining external funding (25%), difficulty in finding partners (39%) and a lack of skilled workers (61%) as major deterrences to innovation.
3 According to OECD (2017), on average only 13% of innovating SMEs (<250 employees) achieve their innovation in collaboration with universities or research institutes, compared to 31% for large firms (p. 134). Moreover, in each country, SMEs are also less likely to collaborate with business partners than large firms are (p. 135).

References

Almus, M. and Czarnitzki, D. (2003), The effects of public R&D subsidies on firms’ innovation activities: The case of Eastern Germany. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 21 (2), 226-236.

Alstadsæter , A., Barrios, S., Nicodème, G., Skonieczna, A.M. and Vezzani, A. (2018), Patent boxes design, patents location and local R&D. Economic Policy 33 (93), 131-177.

Banal-Estañol, A., Macho-Stadler, I. and Pérez-Castrillo, D. (2017), Endogenous matching in university-industry collaboration: Theory and empirical evidence from the United Kingdom. Management Science 64 (4), 1591-1608.

Beck, T. and Demirguc-Kunt, A. (2006), Small and medium-size enterprises: Access to finance as a growth constraint. Journal of Banking and Finance 30 (11), 2931-2943.

Bertoni, F., Colombo, M.G. and Quas, A. (2015), The patterns of venture capital investment in Europe. Small Business Economics 45 (3), 543-560.

Ceccagnoli, M., Graham, S.J., Higgins, M.J. and Lee, J. (2010), Productivity and the role of complementary assets in firms’ demand for technology innovations. Industrial and Corporate Change 19 (3), 839-869.

Cockburn, I. and Henderson, R. (2001), Scale and scope in drug development: Unpacking the advantages of size in pharmaceutical research. Journal of Health Economics 20 (6), 1033-1057.

Colombo, M.G., Cumming, D.J. and Vismara, S. (2016), Governmental venture capital for innovative young firms. Journal of Technology Transfer 41 (1), 10-24.

De la Torre, A., Martinez Peria, M.S. and Schmukler, S.L. (2010), Bank involvement with SMEs: Beyond relationship lending. Journal of Banking and Finance 34 (9), 2280-2293.

Dechezleprêtre, A., Einiö, E., Martin, R., Nguyen, K.T. and Van Reenen, J. (2016), Do tax incentives for research increase firm innovation? An RD design for R&D. NBER Working Paper No. 22405.

Edler, J. and Yeow, J. (2016), Connecting demand and supply: The role of intermediation in public procurement of innovation. Research Policy 45 (2), 414-426.

Farre-Mensa, J., Hegde, D. and Ljungqvist. A. (2016), The bright side of patents. NBER Working Paper No. 21959.

Georghiou, L., Edler, J., Uyarra. E. and Yeow, J. (2014), Policy instruments for public procurement of innovation: Choice, design and assessment. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 86, 1-12.

Griffith, R. and Miller, H. (2010), Support for Research and Innovation. In: Chote, R., Emmerson, C. and Shaw, J. (Eds.), IFS Green Budget: February 2010. IFS Commentary 112.

Griffith, R., Miller, H. and O’Connell, M. (2014), Ownership of intellectual property and corporate taxation. Journal of Public Economics 112, 12-23.

Guerzoni, M. and Raiteri, E. (2015), Demand-side vs. supply-side technology policies: Hidden treatment and new empirical evidence on the policy mix. Research Policy 44 (3), 726-747.

Hall, B.H. and Lerner, J. (2010), The financing of R&D and innovation. In: Hall, B.H. and Rosenberg, N. (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Innovation. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 610-639.

Hall, B.H., Helmers, C., Rogers, M. and Sena, V. (2013), The importance (or not) of patents to UK Firms. Oxford Economic Papers 65 (3), 603-629.

Hall, B.H., Mairesse, J. and Mohnen, P. (2010), Measuring the returns to R&D. In: Hall, B.H. and Rosenberg, N. (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Innovation. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1033-1082.

Hall, B.H. and Ziedonis, R.H. (2001), The patent paradox revisited: An empirical study of patenting in the U.S. semiconductor industry, 1979-1995. RAND Journal of Economics 32 (1), 101-128

Harhoff, D., Hoisl, K., Reichl, B. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2009), Patent validation at the country level: The role of fees and translation costs. Research Policy 38 (9), 1423-1437.

Helmers, C. and Rogers, M. (2011), Does patenting help high-tech start-ups? Research Policy 40 (7), 1016-1027.

Hottenrott, H. and Peters, B. (2012), Innovative capability and financing constraints for innovation: More money, more innovation? Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (4), 1126-1142.

Huggins, R. and Johnston, A. (2009), Knowledge networks in an uncompetitive region: SME innovation and growth. Growth and Change 40 (2), 227-259.

Hughes, A. and Mina, A. (2010), The impact of the patent system on SMEs. Centre for Business Research. University of Cambridge Working Paper No.411.

Hyytinen, A. and Toivanen, O. (2005), Do financial constraints hold back innovation and growth? Evidence on the role of public policy. Research Policy 34 (9), 1385-1403.

Kaufmann, A. and Tödtling, F. (2002), How effective is innovation support for SMEs? An analysis of the region of Upper Austria. Technovation 22 (3), 147-159.

Keizer, J.A., Dijkstra, L. and Halman, J. (2002), Explaining innovative efforts of SMEs: An exploratory survey among SMEs in the mechanical and electrical engineering sector in The Netherlands. Technovation 22 (1), 1-13.

Kim, Y., Oh, I. and Lee, J.-D. (2015), Economic impact assessment of public-private matching fund programs using firm-level data. Singapore Economic Review 60 (4), 1-25.

Koga, T. (2005), R&D subsidy and self-financed R&D: The case of Japanese high-technology start-ups. Small Business Economics 24 (1), 53-62.

Lanjouw, J.O. and Schankerman, M. (2004), Protecting intellectual property rights: Are small firms handicapped? Journal of Law and Economics 47 (1), 45-74.

Lerner, J. (2002), When bureaucrats meet entrepreneurs: The design of effective “Public Venture Capital” programmes. Economic Journal 112 (477), 73-84.

Mancusi, M.L. and Vezzulli, A. (2014), R&D and credit rationing in SMEs. Economic Inquiry 52 (3), 1153-1172.

Martin, P., Mayer, T. and Mayneris, F. (2011), Public support to clusters: A firm level study of French “Local Productive Systems”. Regional Science and Urban Economics 41 (2), 108-123.

Meuleman, M. and De Maeseneire, W. (2012), Do R&D subsidies affect SMEs’ access to external financing? Research Policy 41 (3), 580-591.

Mindruta, D. (2013), Value creation in university-firm research collaborations: A matching approach. Strategic Management Journal 34 (6), 644-665.

Nagaoka, S., Nishimura, J., Akaike, S. and Hosono, M. (2014), Making university and industry collaboration: Sources of seeds, needs and their matching in Japan. Paper presented at the international workshop “Exploring Science Sources of Innovations”, Tokyo, Japan.

Nishimura, J. and Okamuro, H. (2011), Subsidy and networking: The effects of direct and indirect support programs of the cluster policy. Research Policy 40 (5), 714-727.

Nishimura, J. and Okamuro, H. (2016), Knowledge and rent spillovers through government-sponsored R&D consortia. Science and Public Policy 43 (2), 207-225.

Nishimura, J. and Okamuro, H. (2018), Internal and external discipline: The effect of project leadership and government monitoring on the performance of publicly funded R&D consortia. Research Policy 47 (5), 840-853.

Nishimura, J., Tsai, Y. and Nagaoka, S. (2018), Impact of initial seeds on the growth of biotechnology startups: Evidence from the U.S. and Japan. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, forthcoming.

NISTEP (National Institute of Science and Technology Policy). (2016), Report on the fourth round of the Japanese National Innovation Survey (J-NIS 2015). NISTEP Report No. 170 (in Japanese).

OECD (2015), The innovation imperative: Contributing to productivity, growth and well-being. Paris: OECD Publishing.

OECD (2017), Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2017 : The digital transformation. Paris: OECD Publishing.

Okamuro, H. (2007), Determinants of successful R&D cooperation in Japanese small businesses: The impact of organizational and contractual characteristics. Research Policy 36 (10), 1529-1544.

Okamuro, H., Kato, M. and Honjo, Y. (2011), Determinants of R&D cooperation in Japanese start-ups. Research Policy 40 (5), 728-738.

Okamuro, H. and Nishimura, J. (2015), Local management of national cluster policies: Comparative case studies of Japanese, German, and French biotechnology clusters. Administrative Sciences 5 (4), 213-239.

Okamuro, H. and Nishimura, J. (2018), Whose business is your project? A comparative study of different subsidy policy schemes for collaborative R&D. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 127, 85-96.

Olander, H., Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, P. and Mähönen, J. (2009), What’s small size got to do with it? Protection of intellectual assets in SMEs. International Journal of Innovation Management 13 (3), 349-370.

Ortega-Argilés, R., Vivarelli, M. and Voigt, P. (2009), R&D in SMEs: a paradox? Small Business Economics 33 (1), 3-11.

O’Sullivan, E., Andreoni, A., López-Gómez, C. and Gregory, M. (2013), What is new in the new industrial policy? A manufacturing systems perspective. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 29 (2), 432-462.

Rao, N. (2016), Do tax credits stimulate R&D spending? The effect of the R&D tax credit in its first decade. Journal of Public Economics 140, 1-12.

Rassenfosse, G. and Jaffe, A.B. (2017), Are patent fees effective at weeding out low-quality patents? Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 27 (1), 134-148.

Rodwell, S., Van Eeckhout, P., Reid, A. and Walendowski, J. (2007), Effects of counterfeiting on EU SMEs and a review of various public and private IPR enforcement initiatives and resources. Final Report to the Enterprise and Industry Directorate-General Directorate B1 – Development of Industrial Policy.

Romero-Jordán, D., Delgado-Rodríguez, M.J., Álvarez-Ayuso, I. and de Lucas-Santos, S. (2014), Assessment of the public tools used to promote R&D investment in Spanish SMEs. Small Business Economics 43 (4), 959-976.

Saastamoinen, J., Reijonen, H. and Tammi, T. (2018), Should SMEs pursue public procurement to improve innovative performance? Technovation 69, 2-14.

Stam, E. (2018), Enabling creative destruction: An entrepreneurial ecosystem approach to policy. U.S.E. Working Paper Series No. 18-05. Utrecht School of Economics.

Suzuki, J. (2017), To support R&D or linkages? Seeking a better policy mix for SME support. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 17-E-098.

Teirlinck, P. and Spithoven, A. (2013), Research collaboration and R&D outsourcing: Different R&D personnel requirements in SMEs. Technovation 33 (4-5), 142-153.

Terziovski, M. (2010), Innovation practice and its performance implications in small and medium enterprises (SMEs) in the manufacturing sector: A resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal 31 (8), 892-902.

Thomson, R. (2017), The effectiveness of R&D tax credits. Review of Economics and Statistics 99 (3), 544-549.

Toder, E.J. (2000), Tax cuts or spending-Does it make a difference? National Tax Journal 53 (3), 361-371.

Warwick, K. and Nolan, A. (2014), Evaluation of industrial policy: Methodological issues and policy lessons. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers No. 16.